>
In economics, a business is a legally-recognized organizational entity existing within an
economically free country designed to sell goods and/or services to consumers or other
businesses, usually in an effort to generate profit.In predominantly capitalist economies, where
most businesses are privately owned, businesses are typically formed to earn profit and grow the
personal wealth of their owners. The owners and operators of a business have as one of their
main objectives the receipt or generation of a financial return in exchange for their work and their
acceptance of risk. Notable exceptions to this rule include cooperative businesses and
government institutions. This model of business functioning is contrasted with socialistic
systems, which involve either government, public, or worker ownership of most sizable
businesses.
The etymology of business relates to the state of being busy either as an individual or society,
doing commercially viable and profitable work. The term business has at least three usages,
depending on the scope — the singular usage above to mean a particular company or
corporation, the generalized usage to refer to a particular market sector, such as the record
business, or the broadest meaning to include all activity by the community of suppliers of goods
and services. However, the exact definition of business, like much else in the philosophy of
business, is a matter of debate.Business Studies, the study of the management of individuals
organizing to maintain collective productivity toward accomplishing particular creative and
productive goals usually to generate profit, is taught as an academic subject in many schools.
Basic forms of ownership
Although forms of business ownership vary by country and local government, there are several
common forms of business ownership:Sole proprietorship: A sole proprietorship is a business
owned by one person. The owner may operate on his or her own or may employ others. The owner
of the business has total and unlimited personal liability of the debts incurred by the business.
Partnership: A partnership is a form of business in which two or more people operate for the
common goal of making profit. Each partner has total and unlimited personal liability of the debts
incurred by the partnership. There are three typical classifications of partnerships: general
partnerships, limited partnerships, and limited liability partnerships. Corporation: A business
corporation is a for-profit, limited liability entity that has a separate legal personality from its
members. A corporation is owned by multiple shareholders and is overseen by a board of
directors, which hires the business's managerial staff. Cooperative: Often referred to as a Co-Op
business or Co-Op, a cooperative is a for-profit, limited liability entity that differs from a
corporation in that it has members, as opposed to shareholders, who share decision-making
authority. Cooperatives are typically classified as either consumer cooperatives or worker
cooperatives. Cooperatives are fundamental to the ideology of economic democracy.
There are many types of businesses, and, as a result, businesses can be classified in many ways.
One of the most common focuses on the primary profit-generating activities of a business:
Manufacturers produce products, from raw materials or component parts, which they then sell at a
profit. Companies that make physical goods, such as cars or pipes, are considered
manufacturers. Service businesses offer intangible goods or services and typically generate a
profit by charging for labor or other services provided to government, other businesses or
consumers. Organizations ranging from house decorators to consulting firms to restaurants and
even to entertainers are types of service businesses. Retailers and Distributors act as middle-men
in getting goods produced by manufacturers to the intended consumer, generating a profit as a
result of providing sales or distribution services. Most consumer-oriented stores and catalogue
companies are distributors or retailers. See also: Franchising Agriculture and mining businesses
are concerned with the production of raw material, such as plants or minerals. Financial
businesses include banks and other companies that generate profit through investment and
management of capital. Information businesses generate profits primarily from the resale of
intellectual property and include movie studios, publishers and packaged software companies.
Utilities produce public services, such as heat, electricity, or sewage treatment, and are usually
government chartered. Real estate businesses generate profit from the selling, renting, and
development of properties, homes, and buildings. Transportation businesses deliver goods and
individuals from location to location, generating a profit on the transportation costshere are many
other divisions and subdivisions of businesses. The authoritative list of business types for North
America although it is widely used around the world is generally considered to be the North
American Industry Classification System, or NAICS. The equivalent European Union list is the
NACE.
Economics
Economics is the social science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of
goods and services. The term economics comes from the Greek for oikos house and nomos
custom or law, hence rules of the household.A definition that captures much of modern
economics is that of Lionel Robbins in a essay: the science which studies human behaviour as a
relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses. Scarcity means that
available resources are insufficient to satisfy all wants and needs. Absent scarcity and alternative
uses of available resources, there is no economic problem. The subject thus defined involves the
study of choices as they are affected by incentives and rsources.Areas of economics may be
divided or classified into various types, including microeconomics and macroeconomics
positive economics what is and normative economics what ought to be mainstream economics
and heterodox economics fields and broader categories within economics.
One of the uses of economics is to explain how economies, as economic systems, work and what
the relations are between economic players agents in the larger society. Methods of economic
analysis have been increasingly applied to fields that involve people officials included making
choices in a social context, such as crime, education, the family, health, law, politics, religion,
social institutions, and war.Although discussions about production and distribution have a long
history, economics in its modern sense is conventionally dated from the publication of Adam
Smith's The Wealth of Nations in . In this work Smith describes the subject in these practical and
exacting terms: Political economy, considered as a branch of the science of a statesman or
legislator, proposes two distinct objects: first, to supply a plentiful revenue or product for the
people, or, more properly, to enable them to provide such a revenue or subsistence for
themselves; and secondly, to supply the state or commonwealth with a revenue sufficient for the
public services. It proposes to enrich both the people and the sovereign.Smith referred to the
subject as 'political economy', but that term was gradually replaced in general usage by
'economics' after .
Microeconomics
Microeconomics or price theory is a branch of economics that studies how individuals,
households, and firms make decisions to allocate limited resources, typically in markets where
goods or services are being bought and sold.Microeconomics examines how these decisions and
behaviours affect the supply and demand for goods and services, which determines prices; and
how prices, in turn, determine the supply and demand of goods and services.Macroeconomics,
on the other hand, involves the sum total of economic activity, dealing with the issues of growth,
inflation, and unemployment and with national economic policies relating to these issues and the
effects of government actions e.g., changing taxation levels on them. Particularly in the wake of
the Lucas critique, much of modern macroeconomic theory has been built upon
'microfoundations' — i.e. based upon basic assumptions about micro-level behaviour.
One of the goals of microeconomics is to analyze market mechanisms that establish relative
prices amongst goods and services and allocation of limited resources amongst many alternative
uses. Microeconomics analyzes market failure, where markets fail to produce efficient results, as
well as describing the theoretical conditions needed for perfect competition. Significant fields of
study in microeconomics include general equilibrium, markets under asymmetric information,
choice under uncertainty and economic applications of game theory. Also considered is the
elasticity of products within the market system.
Assumptions and definitions
The theory of supply and demand usually assumes that markets are perfectly competitive. This
implies that there are many buyers and sellers in the market and none of them have the capacity
to significantly influence prices of goods and services. In many real-life transactions, the
assumption fails because some individual buyers or sellers or groups of buyers or sellers do have
the ability to influence prices. Quite often a sophisticated analysis is required to understand the
demand-supply equation of a good. However, the theory works well in simple situations.
Mainstream economics does not assume a priori that markets are preferable to other forms of
social organization. In fact, much analysis is devoted to cases where so-called market failures
lead to resource allocation that is suboptimal by some standard highways are the classic example,
profitable to all for use but not directly profitable for anyone to finance. In such cases, economists
may attempt to find policies that will avoid waste directly by government control, indirectly by
regulation that induces market participants to act in a manner consistent with optimal welfare, or
by creating missing markets to enable efficient trading where none had previously existed. This is
studied in the field of collective action. It also must be noted that optimal welfare usually takes on
a Paretian norm, which in its mathematical application of Kaldor-Hicks Method, does not stay
consistent with the Utilitarian norm within the normative side of economics which studies
collective action, namely public choice. Market failure in positive economics microeconomics is
limited in implications without mixing the belief of the economist and his or her theory.The
demand for various commodities by individuals is generally thought of as the outcome of a
utility-maximizing process. The interpretation of this relationship between price and quantity
demanded of a given good is that, given all the other goods and constraints, this set of choices is
that one which makes the consumer happiest.
Modes of operation
It is assumed that all firms are following rational decision-making, and will produce at the
profit-maximizing output. Given this assumption, there are four categories in which a firm's profit
may be considered. A firm is said to be making an economic profit when its average total cost is
less than the price of each additional product at the profit-maximizing output. The economic profit
is equal to the quantity output multiplied by the difference between the average total cost and the
price. A firm is said to be making a normal profit when its economic profit equals zero. This occurs
where average total cost equals price at the profit-maximizing output. If the price is between
average total cost and average variable cost at the profit-maximizing output, then the firm is said
to be in a loss-minimizing condition. The firm should still continue to produce, however, since its
loss would be larger if it were to stop producing. By continuing production, the firm can offset its
variable cost and at least part of its fixed cost, but by stopping completely it would lose the
entirety of its fixed cost. If the price is below average variable cost at the profit-maximizing output,
the firm should go into shutdown. Losses are minimized by not producing at all, since any
production would not generate returns significant enough to offset any fixed cost and part of the
variable cost. By not producing, the firm loses only its fixed cost. By losing this fixed cost the
company faces a challenge. It must either exit the market or remain in the market and risk a
complete loss.
In microeconomics, the term market failure does not mean that a given market has ceased
functioning. Instead, a market failure is a situation in which a given market does not efficiently
organize production or allocate goods and services to consumers. Economists normally apply the
term to situations where the inefficiency is particularly dramatic, or when it is suggested that
non-market institutions would provide a more desirable result. On the other hand, in a political
context, stakeholders may use the term market failure to refer to situations where market forces
do not serve the public interest.This situation was first described by Kenneth J. Arrow in a seminal
article on health care in entitled Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care, in the
American Economic Review. George Akerlof later used the term asymmetric information in his
work The Market for Lemons. Akerlof noticed that, in such a market, the average value of the
commodity tends to go down, even for those of perfectly good quality, because the buyer has no
way of knowing whether the product they are buying will turn out to be a lemon a defective
product.
The four main types or causes of market failure are: Monopolies or other cases of abuse of
market power where a single buyer or seller can exert significant influence over prices or output.
Abuse of market power can be reduced by using antitrust regulations. Externalities, which occur
in cases where the market does not take into account the impact of an economic activity on
outsiders. There are positive externalities and negative externalities. Positive externalities occur
in cases such as when a television program on family health improves the public's health.
Negative externalities occur in cases such as when a company’s processes pollutes air or
waterways. Negative externalities can be reduced by using government regulations, taxes, or
subsidies, or by using property rights to force companies and individuals to take the impacts of
their economic activity into account.Public goods such as national defence and public health
initiatives such as draining mosquito-breeding marshes. For example, if draining
mosquito-breeding marshes was left to the private market, far fewer marshes would probably be
drained. To provide a good supply of public goods, nations typically use taxes that compel all
residents to pay for these public goods due to scarce knowledge of the positive externalities to
third parties/social welfare; and Cases where there is asymmetric information or uncertainty
information inefficiency. Information asymmetry occurs when one party to a transaction has more
or better information than the other party. Typically it is the seller that knows more about the
product than the buyer, but this is not always the case. Buyers in some markets have better
information than the Sellers. For example, used-car salespeople may know whether a used car
has been used as a delivery vehicle or taxi, information that may not be available to buyers. An
example of a situation where the buyer may have better information than the seller would be an
estate sale of a house, as required by a last will and testament. A real estate broker purchasing
this house may have more information about the house than the family members of the deceased.
Opportunity cost
Although opportunity cost can be hard to quantify, the effect of opportunity cost is universal and
very real on the individual level. In fact, this principle applies to all decisions, not just economic
ones. Since the work of the Austrian economist Friedrich von Wieser, opportunity cost has been
seen as the foundation of the marginal theory of value.Opportunity cost is one way to measure the
cost of something. Rather than merely identifying and adding the costs of a project, one may also
identify the next best alternative way to spend the same amount of money. The forgone profit of
this next best alternative is the opportunity cost of the original choice. A common example is a
farmer that chooses to farm his land rather than rent it to neighbors, wherein the opportunity cost
is the forgone profit from renting. In this case, the farmer may expect to generate more profit
himself. Similarly, the opportunity cost of attending university is the lost wages a student could
have earned in the workforce, rather than the cost of tuition, books, and other requisite items
whose sum makes up the total cost of attendance. The opportunity cost of a vacation in the
Bahamas might be the down payment money for a house.
Note that opportunity cost is not the sum of the available alternatives, but rather the benefit of the
single, best alternative. Possible opportunity costs of the city's decision to build the hospital on its
vacant land are the loss of the land for a sporting center, or the inability to use the land for a
parking lot, or the money that could have been made from selling the land, or the loss of any of
the various other possible uses—but not all of these in aggregate. The true opportunity cost
would be the forgone profit of the most lucrative of those listed.One question that arises here is
how to assess the benefit of dissimilar alternatives. We must determine a dollar value associated
with each alternative to facilitate comparison and assess opportunity cost, which may be more or
less difficult depending on the things we are trying to compare. For example, many decisions
involve environmental impacts whose dollar value is difficult to assess because of scientific
uncertainty. Valuing a human life or the economic impact of an Arctic oil spill involves making
subjective choices with ethical implications.
Applied microeconomics
Applied microeconomics includes a range of specialized areas of study, many of which draw on
methods from other fields. Much applied works uses little more than the basics of price theory,
supply and demand. Industrial organization and regulation examines topics such as the entry and
exit of firms, innovation, role of trademarks. Law and economics applies microeconomic
principles to the selection and enforcement of competing legal regimes and their relative
efficiencies. Labor economics examines wages, employment, and labor market dynamics. Public
finance also called public economics examines the design of government tax and expenditure
policies and economic effects of these policies e.g., social insurance programs. Political economy
examines the role of political institutions in determining policy outcomes. Health economics
examines the organization of health care systems, including the role of the health care workforce
and health insurance programs. Urban economics, which examines the challenges faced by cities,
such as are sprawl, air and water pollution, traffic congestion, and poverty, draws on the fields of
urban geography and sociology. The field of financial economics examines topics such as the
structure of optimal portfolios, the rate of return to capital, econometric analysis of security
returns, and corporate financial behavior. The field of economic history examines the evolution of
the economy and economic institutions, using methods and techniques from the fields of
economics, history, geography, sociology, psychology, and political science.